Yankee Chicanery on Antebellum Tariffs

(July 6, 2018) Suppose Congress enacted a law setting income tax rates at a flat ten percent for everyone. Assume that future historians characterize any contemporaries who opposed the law for being unfairly high as undeniably greedy and  that any statues to such persons should be destroyed. Finally, suppose that the future historians deliberately fail to tell students that the law had a deceptive provision. Specifically, it stipulated that anyone making more than $100,000 annually was required to be taxed as if their income was a minimum of one million dollars a year. Thus, someone earning only $125,000 would be required to pay four-fifths of their gross income as taxes. That’s precisely the type of deception some modern historians use when the dismiss regional differences over the tariff as a cause of the Civil War.

[Learn more Civil War and Reconstruction at My Amazon Author Page]

During the antebellum era tariffs accounted for about ninety-percent of federal tax revenues. Thus, they were certain to be a major conflict point between the importing and exporting regions of our country. Northerners generally wanted high tariffs on manufactured goods so that their factories could avoid competing on price with less costly merchandise manufactured overseas, most notably Europe. Southerners objected to paying the higher prices for finished goods, regardless of whether the prices resulted directly from the customs tax on imports or the artificially inflated price of domestic manufactured goods protected from European competition by such tariffs. They also objected to high tariffs because the European buyers of their cotton resented that the USA tariffs cut American demand for imported manufactured goods from Europe.

Antebellum New England Cotton Mill Owner Enjoying His Tariff Protection

Since high tariff rates were unfair to all American consumers as well as the South’s export economy, Northern tariff advocates used trickery to make the rates look lower than they really were. One technique used minimum valuations. Thus, while a tariff might be set at a fixed percentage it might also require that the nominal rate be applied to the applicable import at a “minimum valuation” that was above the market value.

Consider, for example, the impact of minimum valuations on the tariffs paid for imported finished cotton cloth between the 1842 Black Tariff and the 1846 Walker Tariff. Domestically, such cloth was made in New England—not the South—while the biggest overseas supplier was Great Britain, which was also the World’s most economical producer.

Northern protectionists were responsible for the high Black Tariff. It so sharply increased effective rates that it forced a 50% drop in imports that caused a steep decline in tariffs collected, despite the higher rates. As one example the Black Tariff placed a nominal import duty on finished cotton cloth of about 25%, but it also mandated a minimum valuation on such cloth that was more than twice the market price. Therefore, the effective tariff rate was actually 57%. It not only shut-out British competition but it angered the Brits so much that they sought alternate raw cotton sources other than the American South. When the Black Tariff was replaced by the lower Walker Tariff in 1846, the nominal rate on finished cotton cloth remained 25% but the minimum valuation was eliminated. Thus, the effective rate on imported cotton cloth dropped from 57% to 25%.*

In short, the Yankee-promoted Black Tariff falsely represented a 57% tariff as 25% whereas the truth-in-advertising Walker Tariff represented its 25% rate for the 25% it really was. Southern congressmen voted ten-to-one against the Black Tariff whereas they voted four-to-one in favor of the lower Walker Tariff.**

*Douglas Irwin and Peter Temin, “The Antebellum Tariffs on Cotton Textiles Revisited,” The Journal of Economic History, V61, N3 (September, 2001), 780

**The United States Tariff of 1861 With an Historical Sketch (New York: Merchant’s Magazine, 1861), 581

Advertisements

3 thoughts on “Yankee Chicanery on Antebellum Tariffs

  1. Christopher Coleman

    A nice concise piece on an important topic. With all the controversy over the looming current tariff wars, it set my mind on the tariff controversies of the ante-bellum period. On my own blog I have pointed out that the 1860 Secession Crisis was only the latest in a series of such crises. The previous Secession movements had nothing to do with slavery but they all revolved around economics. Count Otto vonBismarck was of the opinion that the 1860 Secession crisis was engineered by British bankers, a viewpoint studiously ignored by most historians. Karl Marx, who was a columnist for the NY Tribune up to 1862, described cotton-based slavery as the “pivot” upon which capitalism (primarily British capitalism) grew. Although I still lack facts to back it up, I’m beginning to wonder if the old Prussian wasn’t onto something. As the saying goes, “follow the money”–and who stood most to gain from the South seceding from the Union? There were a number of southern slave owners who opposed secession, knowing that once they left the Union, even if successful, southern slaves would be able to escape to the north with impunity, and if not successful, it meant the end of the institution of slavery. At the very least, historians need to take a closer look at the relationship between Britain, tariffs and the road to secession.

    Reply
  2. Norm

    Did the North ever suffer due to their own tariffs ? It sounds like they shot themselves in the foot.

    Reply
    1. Phil Leigh Post author

      To a far less extent. The protected industries and their workers benefitted from the tariffs. As a result, the rest of the Yankees had to pay more for manufactured goods just as did Southerns. However, they did not need to fear a boycott of their exports by the Europeans because the South accounted for 80% of exports.

      Reply

Leave a Reply

Fill in your details below or click an icon to log in:

WordPress.com Logo

You are commenting using your WordPress.com account. Log Out /  Change )

Google+ photo

You are commenting using your Google+ account. Log Out /  Change )

Twitter picture

You are commenting using your Twitter account. Log Out /  Change )

Facebook photo

You are commenting using your Facebook account. Log Out /  Change )

Connecting to %s

This site uses Akismet to reduce spam. Learn how your comment data is processed.